Competitive Contracting in the US: Overcoming
Barriers
Paper Presented by
Jean Love & Jim Seal
to the
Second International Conference on Competition and Ownership in
Public Transport
Tampere, Finland
June 1991
Competitive contracting (tendering) for transit service in
the United States first received
national attention in the late 1970s in San Diego, California.
Since then, the practice has
spread to all regions of the country. Contracted services save,
on average, 30 percent compared
with publicly produced service, and savings in some localities
have been as high as 60 percent.
And while there have been some failures, in general,
competitively contracted service has
proved to be equal or superior to publicly produced service with
regard to safety and reliability
and superior to publicly produced service in flexibility.
Yet, after more than a decade and after scores of labor
arbitration hearings, court
disputes, and legislative battles, only eight percent of total
public transit bus service in the US
is provided through competitive contract. In contrast, more than
70 percent of demand
responsive (dial-a-ride) service for the elderly and disabled and
30 percent of school bus services
is provided through competitive contract.
The reluctance to convert to competitive contracting of
public transit is related to the
organization and funding structure of public transit service
delivery, to the barriers thus
created, and to the social, economic, and political milieu of
urban mass transportation in the
US.
To the Reader The text, which follows, does not include a
comprehensive survey of
the evidence for the benefits of competitive contracting of
public transit service in the United
States. The reader is referred to the many studies and
publications that present the evidence
to date. In addition, the paper addresses only regular bus
service open to the general public
and does not include special transportation services such as
those for the elderly and disabled
known as demand responsive or dial-a-ride services. To avoid, as
much as is possible,
needlessly confusing or overburdening the reader, the paper is a
simplified overview of the
current barriers to competitive contracting and the strategies
used to surmount those barriers;
therefore, clarifications as well as references have been
relegated to endnotes.
US PUBLIC TRANSIT STRUCTURE
The most common way countries convert from publicly-produced
transit service to
competitive contracting of service is through passage of national
legislation. While this may
not obviate difficult legislative battles or expensive transition
costs, it does escalate the
transition and avoid the multiple state and local court cases,
arbitration hearings, and legislative
campaigns that have occurred in the US. Public transit agencies
in the US are quasi-governmental public monopolies, some even
have the right to levy taxes. Nonetheless, transit
agencies are funded by and regulated by all levels of government.
Conversion to competitive
contracting usually does not involve a relatively simple change
in law or policy at one level
of government, nor is there a single pattern for conversion.
For, despite similarities, there are
endless variations of structure and regulation that pertain to
the public transit agency
depending on state and local laws as well as the unique structure
and location of the agency
itself.
In the US, federal (national) assistance to transit is
relatively minor; only 10 percent of
total public transit (bus) operating costs is provided by the
federal government. But, federal
assistance provides almost 62 percent of capital assistance.
This federal contribution has an
undue influence on the total costs of transit services as well as
on the barriers to competitive
contracting. In addition, the federal government spurred the
conversion of transit from
regulated private franchised monopolies to local public
monopolies and thus influenced the
design and functioning of public transit agencies.
The Federal Urban Mass Transportation Act In 1964,
Congress passed the Urban
Mass Transportation Act that transformed unsubsidized transit
service by regulated private
monopoly to subsidized transit service by public monopolies and
determined the shape of
transit authorities across the nation. Concerned about the
precipitous drop in transit ridership
that was driving many of the nation's franchised private transit
companies into bankruptcy,
the federal government provided capital funds through the new
Urban Mass Transportation
Administration (UMTA) to help localities buy the failing private
companies. These federal
dollars require(d) local or state matching funds. A decade
later, UMTA began to partially fund
public transit operating deficits.
UMTA is empowered to distribute funds to "designated
recipients" most often,
transit authorities. Sometimes, as in California, metropolitan
planning organizations are the
designated recipient, and they channel the funds directly to the
transit agency. Rarely, city
governments, such as Phoenix, are recipients and the transit
agency is a division of city
government. The choice of designated recipient of federal funds
is determined by the governor
of each state. Otherwise, federal funding for transit bypasses
state governments.
The states, however, often have passed enabling legislation
to create regional transit
districts, which combine central cities and suburban areas into
one service area. In most
instances, suburban areas contribute to regional transit
subsidies based on sales or gasoline tax
receipts or based on some other criteria unrelated to the amount
of service received. In other
instances, suburban areas contract with the regional transit
district for services. Characteris-
tically, both planning and operations of transit service are
provided by the centralized transit
authority, which, most often, is located in the center city.
Although funding most often does not flow directly to the
central city governments,
the central city almost universally dominates the composition of
the board of directors, the
planning and delivery of transit services, the management
culture, and the labor environment
of the regional transit authority. The power of the central city
is enhanced by the formula
used to determine the distribution of the bulk of federal
funding. The formula is based on a
number of factors including population density and public transit
ridership, which skews
power away from lower-density suburbs and toward the city. The
domination of public
transit by the central city has important implications in the US:
central cities are overwhelmingly governed by one party and tend
to be lenient toward the demands of organized labor;
public sector employment tends to be proportionately larger and
more influential in cities than
in suburban areas; and US media is located in the central cities
such that central city concerns,
interests, and biases tend to dominate the local newspaper and
television coverage even when
the total suburban area population exceeds that of the central
city. (Many US cities have only
one major daily newspaper, and most reporters for the major
dailies are union members;
broadcasters are even more heavily unionized).
BARRIERS TO COMPETITIVE CONTRACTING
Public Transit Funding: Less than half of public transit
revenues are derived from
fares and advertising revenues. (Chart: US Transit Operating
Revenues) Nearly 60 percent
of public transit revenues in 1989 were provided by public
subsidies. One-third of the public
aid is contributed by the states, and almost 60 percent is
contributed by local governments
usually through sales or gasoline taxes. While the federal
government provides only 14 percent
of transit operating subsidies, federal assistance amounts to
almost 62 percent of capital public
aid. Transit agencies do not receive pro rata capital sums on an
annual basis. Buses are
required to be kept for twelve years, and they are purchased in
custom lots so that individual
transit agencies receive large grants in some years and
negligible amounts in others. This
method of funding capital expenses accords exceptional power to
the labor unions; the power
is enhanced by large construction grants for facilities and for
popular rail projects.
In many states and municipalities, transit is funded through
dedicated taxes. These
taxes vary from area to area and may be a percentage of sales,
gasoline, or property taxes that,
by law, must accrue to the transit agency, or they may be taxes
directly levied by the transit
agency. In either case, the transit agency does not have to go
through the annual budgeting
process to receive funds from the state, city, or transit
district, nor do they have to compete
for funding with other public services. Dedicated taxes have
been shown to have a cost-escalating effect on the transit agency
by Shughart and Kimenyi.
Public Transit Costs: Public transit costs have escalated
at twice the rate of
inflation since 1970. Before receiving subsidies, public transit
cost increases were close to the
rate of inflation. Today, public transit costs continue to
increase relative to inflation, while
private bus industry costs are declining relative to inflation.
In fact, public transit costs per
mile have increased at a faster pace than US medical costs.
Transit's dependence on local, state, and federal funding
has made it subject to myriad
regulations from all levels of government. Alternatively, no one
governmental entity has been
confronted with the full impact of transit cost escalation. The
willingness of various
governmental entities to cover transit's costs have acted as a
barrier to privatization; public
transit has not felt the need to control its costs.
Power of the Public Sector: The power of public sector
interest groups in America
to garner subsidies has been well documented in the public choice
economics literature.
Public transit employee interests have exerted pressure beyond
the usual concerted efforts of
public sector employees and unions to effect the legislative
process. Most large public transit
agencies pay for full-time lobbyists in Washington as well as in
the state capitol, and transit
management also spends time lobbying. Most large transit agencies
have large, fully developed
public affairs departments. In addition, the American Public
Transit Association, in which
most transit agencies hold membership, is involved in lobbying
activity.
The strength of public transit lobbying efforts is suggested
by patronage, spending, and
service figures. From 1979 to 1989, US employment increased over
21 percent. Because work
trips form the highest proportion of transit trips (transit
provides nearly 6 percent of the work
trips as opposed to 2 percent of all trips), one would expect
that patronage would increase.
Yet, the number of passenger boardings declined by nearly 6
percent; operating costs climbed
almost 36 percent after adjustment for inflation, and the amount
of transit service offered
increased by only 4.9 percent. Subsidies grew by 290 percent to
over $8 billion despite every
indication that transit was not using the bulk of funds to
finance service increases.
Public Sector Labor Unions: Perhaps the biggest barrier
to competitive contracting
is resistance by the transit unions. Transit union power flows
from the influence of public
sector union power in America's largest cities and from public
sector employee compensation
gains especially in state and local governments, but it is also
connected to the special protection
afforded transit unions by the federal legislation that created
public ownership of transit.
Only 16 percent of total employees in the US belonged to
labor unions by 1989.
Except for the large industrial oligopolies, there is little
pattern bargaining and no national
governmental bargaining. Labor union membership in the private
sector has declined from
a high of almost 35 percent in the 1955 to just 12 percent in
1989. Public sector membership
has increased from 13 percent to nearly 40 percent by 1989. This
increase in unionization has
coincided with an increase in public sector pay from parity to
more that 10 above the private
sector.
The pay premium of public sector employees is more
pronounced in public transit,
where unionized drivers are paid up to double that of drivers in
the unionized private sector
and 65 percent more than the average production worker. Transit
drivers, whose jobs require
less than graduation from high school (grammar or secondary
school), receive nearly 11 percent
more in total compensation than employees with four or more years
of college education. The
average compensation for all transit employees exceeds the
average compensation for US
employees with college degrees by more than 30 percent. Public
transit benefits average 50
percent double that of the average private sector worker.
Special Labor Protection: The monopoly power of public
transit labor unions has
been magnified by a particularly expensive provision of Urban
Mass Transportation Act of
1964, and as amended. Section 13(c) of the act requires that
adequate labor arrangements be
made to ensure that employees are not harmed as a result of
federal funding. Under 13(c), the
US Department of Labor must certify annually that adequate
arrangements have been made
to protect labor before any single transit grant can be approved
for operating or capital
expense. This certification process has been interpreted to
require negotiation of special labor
agreements between the transit agency and its union agreements
that are in addition to
existing labor agreements. Public transit unions have sought
concessions from public agencies
that they otherwise could not have obtained through the
collective bargaining process. Failure
of the transit agency to agree to these concessions has resulted
in delay or could result in loss
of federal funding. In essence, Section 13(c) has given transit
labor unions the power of veto
over the coveted capital (and operating) grants.
This second chance at labor protection has added to the monopoly
power of public
transit unions. Most union contracts are silent on the issue of
competitive contracting, but
the threat of lost or delayed federal funding has constrained the
use of competitive contracting.
In addition, one provision of 13(c) requires that an employee
whose job is eliminated due to
economies or efficiencies be provided up to six years' severance
pay. (In the US, only railway
employees have similar protection.) This provision has proved to
be a costly barrier to some
methods of conversion to competitive contracting.
Labor Bargaining
Section 13(c) requires that transit agencies have some method
of
dealing with impasse or the failure of labor and management to
reach accord. Because 13(c)
is not specific on method, transit agencies and unions must
determine methods for the
resolution of differences. Agency to agency variations in
dispute resolution result from
differing state and local laws, but, more often, differences in
methods between transit agencies
are a function of the proclivities of individual transit boards
and management.
In general, impasse may be resolved through binding or
non-binding arbitration,
through strikes, or through court action. Transit unions rarely
resort to strike. Strikes by
public employees are prohibited in some states, which has not
stopped their occurrence. More
importantly, strikes have backfired badly for transit unions.
Because most Americans are not
dependent on public transit for mobility, there is little public
pressure to accede to union
demands. In addition, strikes cause long-lasting loss of
ridership, which could result in loss of
union jobs.
Instead, transit unions have pressured agencies to use
binding arbitration to resolve
disputes and to include this requirement in labor contracts.
Most transit agencies have signed
such contracts. The prevalence of these clauses results from a
model 13(c) agreement
developed jointly by the transit unions and the American Public
Transit Association in 1975,
which specified that disputes be settled by binding arbitration.
While individual agencies were
not required to adopt this contract or its provisions, many did
to avoid lengthy contract
negotiations.
Binding arbitration does not always result in a decision
that is favorable to the union;
but more often than not, arbitration has resulted in positive
gains for the unions when applied
to compensation, hours, or to issues covered by the current
contract. On the issue of
competitive contracting of transit service, arbitration has
resulted in mixed rulings. In general,
rulings against competitive contracting are more likely when a
clause in the present contract
expressly forbids contracting of work. However, there have been
instances where contracts
are silent on contracting and the arbitrator has ruled against
competitive contracting.
Arbitrators also have ruled against competitive contracting when
the transit agency did not
notify the union of proposed intent to contract or when the
transit agency did not bargain in
"good faith."
If the transit labor contract and the state law does not
require binding arbitration, and
if the agency does not agree to voluntary arbitration, impasses
may be taken to court. The
various state laws and the labor contract, then, are the decisive
elements in allowing
competitive contracting. In some states, contracting has been
viewed by the courts as a
management prerogative, and it is not a negotiable item between
labor and management.
Public Transit Managers
Public transit administrators have resisted the competitive
contracting of transit services. Indeed, most instances of
competitive contracting have occurred
as a result of withdrawal from the regional transit district or
as a result of outside pressure
from other legislative or governmental bodies.
It is difficult to ascertain the motivations that underlie
this resistance. Theorists posit
that competitive contracting would result in a diminution of
power resulting from a down-sizing of agencies or from the loss
of funding that might occur if transit could be provided for
less. As in Colorado, management jobs might be lost when
significant portions of service are
competitively contracted, and administrators might suffer reduced
compensation or perquisites
as a result. Whatever the reason, it is clear that public
transit administrators have derived
special benefits from the present system.
Transit managers, as well as transit drivers, routinely are
more highly compensated than
their private sector equivalents. Like drivers, managers'
average benefits are close to 50 percent
of their salaries as compared to 25.7 percent in the private
sector. The average transit
employee receives 70 percent more in compensation than the
average US employee.
The Chicago Transit Authority (CTA) provides a conservative
example of the
differences in compensation. From 1975 to 1988, CTA costs
increased only 19 percent relative
to inflation as compared with the transit industry average of 32
percent. Yet, the director
of the CTA, who is not the most highly paid transit administrator
in the nation, receives more
pay than elected officials like the governor of Illinois, the
mayor of Chicago, and US
Representatives (the highest paid members of Congress) or
appointed officials like the Chicago
police superintendent and fire commissioner.
CONVERSION TO COMPETITIVE CONTRACTING
The unique interaction of transit funding, legal provisions,
and the power of transit
labor unions has created multiple barriers to the conversion to
competitive contracting in the
US. Nonetheless, an increasing number of transit agencies have
begun to contract for services.
The search for ways to overcome the barriers has resulted in a
laboratory of models to convert
to competitive contracting.
Agency Choice
Despite the obstacles, some agencies have decided to convert to
competitive contracting. This has the advantage of full support
by the transit agency reducing
the chance of unfair practices against the private bidders and
contractors. It also has the
advantage of avoiding the loss of federal funding, which can
occur when localities withdraw
from the regional transit district.
Oftentimes, the conversion results in time and costs
expended in labor- initiated binding
arbitration as in the case of Fort Wayne (Indiana) or court suits
as in the case of St. Louis.
In both cities, these actions resulted in findings for
competitive contracting, primarily because
there was no clause in the current contract prohibiting
competitive contracting, the agencies
faced loss of current service in the absence of the cost savings
from competitive contracting,
and there were no layoffs of union personnel as a result of the
action. In cases such as
Houston, where the transit agency competitively contracted for
new service, and metropolitan
San Francisco, where the transit agency competitively contracted
routes that had been sole
source contracts with a private operator, arbitration and court
action was avoided.
Nonetheless, a number of agencies have sought to competitively
contract but were prevented
from doing so through arbitration findings or through court
action.
Federal Support
The administrative level of the Urban Mass Transportation
Administration (UMTA) for the past decade has favored competitive
contracting of transit
service. UMTA's proposed rule to require a portion of each
transit agency's service be
competitively contracted as a condition for receiving federal
funding was rejected by Congress.
Congress did allow the UMTA rules that prohibit public transit
agencies from providing
school bus service and, with limited exceptions, charter and tour
services. These rules helped
to strengthen the private bus industry and allow for their entry
in smaller markets, which
increased the free market foundation needed for conversion to
competitive contracting. To
further promote competitive contracting, UMTA has tried three
basic approaches in addition
to education efforts:
1. A requirement that transit agencies allow for private
sector
involvement in the planning process;
2. The use of discretionary monies to further competitive
contracting; and
3. The funding of demonstration projects to illustrate the
advantages
of competitive contracting.
UMTA currently requires that transit agencies consider the
use of competitive
contracting for new or restructured services and routes. In
addition, transit agencies must
allow for the interaction of the private sector in the planning
process. Theoretically, these
requirements would create a public forum for private operators to
bring agency and public
attention to the savings of competitive contracting.
Of themselves, the requirements have had little impact.
Free of the mandate to
competitively contract, the transit agencies compliantly consider
competitive contracting, but
find it unsuitable for use in their region. And the private
sector has been poorly prepared and
not inclined to spend the money and time to attend planning
meetings or to mount an
expensive active public campaign to promote competitive
contracting. Even where the
private sector has become active in the planning process, the
media rarely have reported the
issues involved, and competitive contracting of transit service
has not become a part of the
public debate.
Transit agencies are more apt to seriously consider
competitive contracting when doing
so will increase their chances of obtaining desirable capital
monies from a discretionary fund.
Several transit agencies, such as Santa Cruz (California), have
initiated competitive contracting
of a portion of their service to receive or increase their
chances of receiving these "demonstration" funds.
Many of these contracted services have been faithfully
executed by the transit agency.
Unfortunately, these grants can only be used to institute new
services and so are applicable to
primarily high-growth areas. In addition, some agencies have
accepted the money and then
been less than honest in bid procedures. UMTA requires that the
agency bid fairly in
competition with the private sector, but, in many cases, the
transit agency has bid below their
attributable, fully allocated costs to be awarded operation of
the route. This violation of
UMTA regulations can be contested by private providers, but it
requires time, money, and
expertise from the private sector. Where the private sector has
protested and where the transit
agency has not bid fairly, UMTA has insisted the agency
reconsider the award or return that
portion of federal funds.
Some transit agencies have applied to receive UMTA pilot
project monies to study the
savings and performance of competitively contracted service. The
funding has provided for
vehicles and facilities that are beyond the ability of the
transit agency to fund from capital
formula grants. The results of these "compelled" conversions
have been mixed. Areas, such
as Los Angeles, that otherwise have been favorable to competitive
contracting have shown
positive benefits from competitive contracting. (See Los Angeles
Case Study.) Both the agency
and the contractors have been pleased with the contracting
relationship. Where the agency
has been reluctant to competitively contract and has done so to
receive the funding, such New
Orleans, competitive contracting has not been as successful. In
New Orleans, for example, the
agency leased to the contract operator buses that had been
discontinued by the manufacturer
for poor performance, that were more than double the average age
of the agency fleet, and that
were beyond their useful life. While the contractor ran the
buses at savings of 53.7 percent
compared to agency operation, the media and the agency complained
about the poor
maintenance and breakdown rate of the vehicles.
UMTA also has provided demonstration funding through its
Entrepreneurial Services
Program Grants to encourage private sector operators to develop
transit services that do not
rely on public subsidies. The grants cover some costs of
planning routes and services and a
small portion of capital assistance. The unsubsidized services
must not be in competition with
the subsidized public transit services. The program has met with
very limited success.
Because of low population densities and low transit ridership in
the US, few transit services
can exist without subsidy. Private operators, too, would have
the added time and expense of
federal reporting requirements for a period of years. Finally,
the federal application process
is cumbersome and can take a year or more.
State Legislation
In the US, changing state law to require competitive contracting
of transit service is closest to the standard model of changing
national law. This method has
the advantage of avoiding multiple settlements of labor
grievances across several jurisdictions
and as privatization increases, although state law is still
subject to review by the state courts.
To avoid conflict with Section 13(c) labor protection clauses,
state law would either require
the conversion of competitive contracting to proceed within the
natural employee attrition
(turnover or wastage) rate and thus avoid employee layoff and
payments for idle workers,or
the law would include provision for retention of idle workers or
payment for up to six years
for those who suffer layoff.
Competitive contacting bills have been introduced in a
number of states, but, to date,
only Colorado has passed legislation that requires competitive
contracting. In 1988, the
Colorado Legislature voted to require the Denver Regional Transit
District to competitively
contract 20 percent of total bus service over the objection of
the transit agency and despite the
fierce lobbying of the unions.
The Denver competitive contracting law, Senate Bill 164,
required that no employees
suffer layoff as a result of the contracting; instead, workers
were to be paid although idle. The
legislation was passed as a demonstration (experimental) project
and required a full independent
audit to be presented to the Legislature. The audit was to
compare public with private safety
and service quality and the full cost of competitive contracting
to the costs that would be
incurred had the agency continued to produce service. The first
parcel of six separate parcels
of service was awarded in 1989.
The revised final audit of Denver competitive contracting
projected savings at 27.5
percent after accounting for the public agency costs of idle
labor and facilities. The audit
reported that service and safety on average were comparable
during the period of study,
although the private contractors were improving. (The period of
study covered approximately
the first year of the operation of service; some contracts had
been operating more than a year,
one had not begun.)
The results of the final revised audit were controversial.
Nonetheless, the audit
demonstrated future savings after accounting for the more than $9
million of short-term costs
of idled labor. When a bill was introduced to increase the
amount of service to be
competitively contracted, however, both the labor unions and the
transit agency publicly
claimed there had been no savings through competitive
contracting, and the bill was defeated.
Withdrawal from Regional Transit District Service A
number of localities have
begun to competitively contract after withdrawing from the
regional transit district or after
discontinuing the routine practice of awarding contracts for
services solely to the nearby transit
agency. Withdrawal has the advantage of full support by the
transit agency as well as
avoidance of labor liabilities and grievances. One disadvantage
of withdrawal is that it can
result in loss of federal funding as in Johnson County (Kansas).
In this case, the regional
transit agency in Kansas City continued to receive full federal
funding for the metropolitan
area of which Johnson County was a part, but since Johnson County
was no longer a part of
the transit district, it forfeited any benefit of federal funding
it otherwise might have received.
Alternatively, Snohomish County (Washington), which qualified for
federal funding in its own
right, discontinued 70 percent of its contracting with the
Seattle transit agency and was able
to retain its federal funding when it began competitive
contracting.
Separation of Policy from Operations
A small number of transit districts have separate
policy and operations boards and staffing. State legislation
created these oversight models to
improve transit management and cost performance. A side effect,
in some cases, has been that
the oversight (or policy) boards have determined that the transit
agency was not the best or
lowest cost producer of transit service. Transit contracting in
Los Angeles, for example, has
followed the creation of separate policy boards. Separation of
policy from operations can
make it easier to convert to competitive contracting if the board
has the will to do so.
However, bureaucratic capture can occur just as easily on the
policy board as on the operations
board.
Private Sector Advocacy Groups
In some areas, private sector bus operators have
formed advocacy groups to promote the use of competitive
contracting. These state or
regional groups, usually through their executive director or
advocate, work to educate the
general public and their elected officials and to influence
public transit agencies to use
competitive contracting. The groups spread costs among a number
of operators, although
there is a problem with free riders.
Advocacy groups provide needed information to both the
transit agency and group
members once the transit agency has made the decision to
competitively contract; the agency
is monitored during the bidding development process to assure
reasonable terms and non-biased
procedures, and private operators as a group receive information
on how to satisfy bid
applications. If the agency violates UMTA regulations (for
example, by bidding below agency
costs), the advocacy group protests, thus removing the onus on
any one private operator and
spreading the costs of protesting. Once the contract has been
awarded, the advocacy group
assists the contractor in contract compliance and applies peer
pressure to laggard contractors
to boost performance. The group also informally monitors the
agency to prevent contractor
harassment.
State and regional advocacy groups have a mixed record with
regard to effectiveness.
In some areas, such as California, an experienced advocate and a
proactive board in
combination with high-growth transit districts has been very
successful in increasing the
amount of competitive contracting. In other areas, boards have
been reluctant to aggressively
pursue conversion to competitive contracting and have limited the
effectiveness of the
advocate, and contracting has not increased. Advocates are
particularly effective when they
can combine efforts with other advocacy groups such as taxpayer
and good government leagues
to pressure transit agencies to convert or to bid fairly.
National advocacy groups have publicized the issue and
otherwise have assisted in the
conversion to competitive contracting. The American Bus
Association, the American
Legislative Exchange Council, and the International Taxicab and
Livery Association have
published reports and newsletters, developed model legislation,
held seminars and conferences,
and have provided legal and technical assistance to operators and
to legislators.
LOS ANGELES: A CASE STUDY
A number of methods have been used in the Los Angeles
metropolitan area to avoid
the obstacles to competitive contracting. The Santa Clarita
Valley was part of the (Southern
California Rapid Transit District the Los Angeles transit
agency) special (transit) taxing
district but withdrew and competitively contracts for transit
service; the City of Los Angeles
withdrew a portion of services from the transit agency and
converted these to competitive
contract; and citizens of the Foothill area petitioned the policy
board (Los Angeles County
Transportation Commission) for a separate transit district to
competitively contract for
services. The conversion to competitive contracting was aided by
an active private sector
advocacy group and its competitive contracting coordinator.
The study will focus on the City of Los Angeles, the County
of Los Angeles, and the
Foothill Transit Zone. To simplify, the City of Los Angeles will
be designated LA; the
County of Los Angeles will be referred to as the County; the
Southern California Rapid
Transit District will denoted as the Transit Agency; the Los
Angeles County Transportation
commission will be designated the Commission; and the Foothill
Transit Zone will be referred
to as Foothill or the zone.
Shuttle and Express Service
In 1985, LA, the Commission, and the Transit Agency
agreed to give LA responsibility for services that had been
provided under contract by the
Transit Agency for 14 years a shuttle service serving the
downtown area and a proposed
express service. LA decided to competitively contract for the
services. During the first year
of competitive operation, ridership on the shuttle service
increased by 10 percent, and private
costs saved 38 percent over transit agency costs. LA expanded
the service, and a two-year
evaluation indicated savings of 60 percent.
Fifteen-route City/County Services In 1986, the Transit
Agency decided to
discontinue a number of unproductive routes. The Commission
decided to transfer
responsibility for operation of the routes to LA and the County.
The action was taken for
a variety of reasons:
1. The Commission, the policy board created by the state
to plan and program all
transportation dollars for the County, was increasingly
dissatisfied with the
Transit Agency's mounting operating costs.
2. The Transit Agency's contracts with the two major labor
unions prohibited
contracting to lower cost private operators to reduce
operating costs.
3. Based on the continuing success of the contracted LA
express and shuttle
services and successfully contracted services in
adjacent municipalities, there was
a growing consensus among the Commissioners that
unproductive service should
be reassigned.
4. UMTA "demonstration grants" of capital assistance were
available to areas that
competitively contracted.
Eleven local and express routes were transferred to LA and
four local and express routes
were transferred to the County from the Transit Agency. Because
of the labor protection
agreements connected with the UMTA legislation, the County
withdrew its application for
a demonstration grant but retained the service. A second year
evaluation of the contracted
routes indicated that operating costs of the routes declined by
51 percent, miles between
roadcalls (vehicle breakdown on the road) increased by 90 to 416
percent, and the accident
rates per 100,000 miles decreased by 31 to 37 percent.
The Foothill Transit Zone
From 1984 to 1985 and subsequent to exhaustive public
hearings, the Commission developed guidelines for the
establishment of transportation zones.
Upon final Commission approval of the guidelines, 29 cities of
the San Gabriel Valley
submitted an application (also preceded by public hearings) for
the creation of a new transit
zone comprised of 35 bus routes and to be known as the Foothill
Transit Zone. If the plan
was approved, operation of the routes would be transferred from
the Transit Agency to the
new zone. The application did not receive the required
two-thirds vote of the Commission.
The plan was resubmitted after reducing the zone to 20 cities and
14 routes (111 buses), and
accepted by the Commission in December of 1987. The zone
represented nine million
estimated boardings and over $90 million in combined subsidies
and fare revenues. The routes
were to be transferred in phases over a two year period so as not
to adversely affect any
Transit Agency employees.
The Commission may have been influenced to accept the
creation of the new zone by
the actions of the Transit Agency, which had been planning to
increase fares by 50 percent
while decreasing service to the Foothill area. The Transit
Agency had not been able to control
its costs, and one estimate of savings resulting from the
transfer of the routes and competitively
contracting for service exceeded $9 million annually.
Operation of the first two Foothill routes was scheduled to
begin July 1, 1988.
However, two Transit Agency unions and the national federation of
unions (AFL-CIO) filed
a lawsuit with the Superior Court, or lower state court, to
prevent Foothill from operating
the routes and to prevent the Commission from funding routes and
using its discretionary
authority to transfer routes from the Transit Agency to the
Foothill Transit Zone. The unions
also argued that the Commission must get the Transit Agency's
consent prior to transferring
the routes. The lower court issued an injunction against the
transfer (of all but two routes
that were already in operation by a private operator) pending the
hearings on the case.
To pressure the Transit Agency to give consent to the
transfer of routes, the
Commission withheld from the Transit Agency over $50 million in
discretionary funding (at
the rate of $9 million per month). The Commission cited as
reason for withholding the funds
the failure of the Transit Agency to abide by the Commission's
guidelines for labor contracts,
which prohibited labor agreements that prevented competitive
contracting for service. Both
the Transit Agency and the labor unions asked the court to issue
an injunction to prevent the
Commission from withholding of discretionary funds. The court
denied the injunction. The
Transit Agency and the Commission then developed an eight-point
plan that included Transit
Agency consent for transfer of the routes.
Hearings on the union lawsuit brought against the Commission
began in May, 1989 and
were concluded a month later. Attorneys for the unions argued
that creation of the Foothill
Zone was inconsistent with state statutes and the labor
agreements with the Transit Agency
as well as with the federal 13(c) agreements signed by the
Commission. Union attorneys
pleaded for a narrow, restrictive interpretation of the state law
that the Commission had used
to create the zone. In July, the court lifted the temporary
injunction, denied permanent
injunction, and rendered its decision: the potential harm to the
area's bus riders that resulted
from not allowing the more cost-effective Foothill Zone to
contract for service far outweighed
the possible adverse affects on Transit Agency employees. Three
more routes were transferred
to Foothill.
The unions appealed the case. The appeals court denied the
union petition for an
injunction against operation of the routes that had been
contracted and the further transfer of
routes and refused to hear the case. The Supreme Court then
issued a temporary injunction
but reversed its decision the following day and remanded the case
back to the appeals court
with instructions to rule on the merits of the injunction, which
would affect the five routes
that had (and have) not been transferred.
A panel of four Appeals Court judges heard arguments in
February, 1991. On April
3, 1991, the California Court of Appeals upheld the decision of
the lower court and ruled in
favor of creation of the transit zone. The Commission estimates
that, to date, its total legal
costs will be just below $1 million; legal costs for all parties
could exceed $3 million. The
unions plan to appeal the decision to the California Supreme
Court. Concurrent with
the decision of the appeals court, auditors were completing a
draft of the required audit of
Foothill's competitive contracts and a comparison of their costs
and performance with that of
the Transit Agency. Preliminary figures indicate total hourly
savings of 40 percent and savings
of subsidy per passenger of 60 percent; ridership on the
contracted routes increased by 20
percent in 1990. Fares are nearly 30 percent lower than those of
the Transit Agency.
(c) 2001 www.publicpurpose.com --- Wendell Cox Consultancy --- Permission granted to use with attribution.
NAVIGATION & PUBLICATION SERIES
|
The Public Purpose     WENDELL COX CONSULTANCY    
Demographia
P. O. Box 841 - Belleville, IL 62269 USA
Telephone: +1.618.632.8507 -
Facsimile: +1.810.821.8134<
|
|