Before the Subcommittee on Railroads Committee
on Transportation and Infrastructure United
States House of Representatives ___________________________________________________ For Release on Delivery 2:00 p.m. EDT Thursday, February 14, 2002 Testimony
of Wendell
Cox, Council
member AMTRAK REFORM COUNCIL SUBMITTED FOR THE RECORD Testimony of Wendell Cox, Member, Amtrak Reform Council Before the House Transportation & Infrastructure Committee, Subcommittee on Railroads 14 February 2002 Mr. Chairman, and members of
the Subcommittee: It
has been an honor for me to serve as an appointee of the US Speaker of the
House of Representatives on the Amtrak Reform Council since January 1999. I
believe that the process established by the Amtrak Reform and Accountability
Act of 1997 was appropriate and only regret that the financial goals included
in that legislation have not been achieved. All of us on the Amtrak Reform
Council hoped that Amtrak would become financially self-sufficient. Moreover, I believe that the
Congressional objective of self-sufficiency was reasonable when enacted, and
remains so today. Amtrak’s fundamental problem is not funding,
it is excessive costs. I thank you for the opportunity to share these
views. Background: Amtrak has been granted
billions in federal subsidies since 1971. As a monopoly, its unit costs have
been exempt from the competition that has improved the performance of airlines,
intercity buses and freight transport. Amtrak has also been a tool of politics.
Unprofitable routes have been operated in response to the political agendas of
members of Congress and even the Amtrak board itself. The
Amtrak Reform and Accountability Act (ARAA) of 1997 requires Amtrak to become
operationally self-sufficient (no federal operating subsidies) by December
2002. That objective will not be met, which has made it necessary for the
Amtrak Reform Council (ARC) to make the ARAA required finding that Amtrak will
not achieve operational self-sufficiency. ARC is now issuing its Action Plan for a “restructured and
rationalized national intercity rail passenger system,” as required by ARAA. Amtrak
does not appear to have taken the self-sufficiency requirement of ARAA
seriously, having acted as if it were “business as usual.” Amtrak has, until
very recently, perpetuated the charade that it was on a “glide-path” to
self-sufficiency. But, under the leadership of new management and a “reform
board,” Amtrak has failed to exercise the new and considerable flexibility
accorded it under ARAA. It is true that Amtrak has improved its operating
revenues somewhat. But it is just as true that Amtrak has outrightly neglected
addressing its excessive expense structure. For post-ARAA Amtrak, it appears
that the answer to every question has been “more money.” Today, as the Action Plan and U.S. Department of
Transportation Inspector General have concluded, Amtrak is no closer to
operating self-sufficiency than it was before the ARAA. Reform
of Amtrak’s dysfunctional organizational and political structure is a
prerequisite to both the operational self-sufficiency required by national
policy and the improvement of passenger rail. The ARC Action Plan proposes important reforms, such as transferring
service authority to state-based corridors and implementation of competitive
franchising. There is US precedent for competitive franchising, which has been
used to provide commuter rail service in Boston, San Francisco, Los Angeles,
San Diego, Miami-Fort Lauderdale-West Palm Beach, Washington, DC and Dallas-Fort
Worth. In some cases, the franchises have been awarded to Amtrak itself. It is
time, as the Action Plan indicates,
for competitive franchising to be extended to intercity rail. I am pleased to
be able to support the Action Plan
because of these important improvements. But
we can do much better in providing the riders and taxpayers of this nation
better transportation within limited public budgets. As a result, I am
outlining revisions that would have made the Action Plan even more effective. These proposals are consistent
with Option 4: Competition and Local
Accountability, which was considered by ARC. More Fundamental Structural
Reform is Required: Under the Action Plan the
National Passenger Rail Corporation (NRPC) would continue to administer the
passenger rail network, and Amtrak would survive as a subsidiary that operates
service. This is unnecessary and creates the potential for continuing the
failed policies of the past. The federal government does not own a commercial
airline or a bus company. And, no public purpose justifies federal ownership of
a passenger rail company. Further,
under the Action Plan, NRPC could
competitively franchise services, and its own subsidiary, the Amtrak operating
company, could compete. It can be expected that managers and employees of the
Amtrak operating company would exert their considerable influence (as before),
both through NRPC and the political process to skew franchise awards in their
direction or even to prevent franchising. International and US experience has
shown that fairness cannot be guaranteed when the organization administering a
procurement is also a competitor (even a subsidiary). Riders
and taxpayers would be better served by establishing a federal Passenger Rail
Transitional Board (PRTB) that would administer transfer of services to
Regional Rail Operating Corporations (owned by states and interstate compacts).
During the transitional period, PRTB would conclude the Amtrak operations
company. The assets that Amtrak currently holds in trust for the riders and
taxpayers would be transferred to the Regional Rail Operating Corporations for
continued public service. The Action
Plan should have proposed more fundamental structural reform by transferring
service oversight to Regional Rail Operating Corporations, while phasing out
Amtrak. Subsidies are Unnecessary: The Action Plan indicates that passenger rail should receive “adequate
and stable” funding. This is an appropriate objective, but only to the extent
that funding is provided by intercity rail users. For example, Wal-Mart (and
other firms) offers sufficient value in goods and services to its customers
that they provide “adequate and stable” funding to pay the operating, capital,
tax and return on investment needs of the company. Similarly, users of the
nation’s intercity highways and commercial air transport systems receive
sufficient value that they provide “adequate and stable” funding for building
and maintaining required infrastructure. But, at least as currently
constituted, intercity passenger rail costs are so high that, even at passenger
fare levels higher than that of intercity highways and airlines (infrastructure
and traffic control are included in passenger fares), customers provide revenue
that is neither adequate nor stable. The Action
Plan inference is that “adequate and stable” funding should be provided by
non-users. This would not be appropriate. Subsidy
by non-users is justified only where there is a compelling public purpose. For
example, national defense, public welfare, education and a host of other
programs provide societal benefits that justify general subsidies, and would be
impossible to fund with user fees. For intercity rail to receive non-user
subsidies would require identification of such a compelling public purpose. Trains are not a Substitute
for Short Distance Air Travel: ARC discussions and the Action Plan have considered short distance air market substitution
as a purpose for subsidizing Amtrak. But, comparatively little short distance
air travel in the United States can be diverted to rail, because demand is so
dispersed and decentralized. Short distance travel markets are overwhelmingly
private vehicle markets (automobiles and sport utility vehicles). Airlines
account for only 0.3 percent of travel over 100 to 200 mile distances and 2.6
percent from 200 to 400 miles (Figure 1). Most current “high speed rail”
proposals would operate at average speeds of barely 80 miles per hour. At such
slow speeds, it is unlikely that the new rail services would be competitive
with airlines for more than three-hour trips (225 air miles). Only 2.1 percent
of US air travel is in such markets outside the Washington-New York-Boston
corridor (which already has frequent rail service). The genuine high-speed rail
services of Japan and Europe operate from 40 percent to 100 percent faster.
Even the 200 mile per hour proposed Florida Overland Express high speed rail
system (canceled by Governor Jeb Bush due to its overly optimistic ridership
projections and high taxpayer cost) would have, based upon promoter
projections, permitted only a two percent reduction in commercial flights
between airports in central and south Florida along the route. Today, Americans travel far more than ever before.
Most of this travel is by airplane. The high volume of airline patronage was
not taken from passenger rail; it was rather created by faster travel and the less expensive fares made possible
through competition (deregulation). Indeed, air travel has been democratized,
making it possible for the overwhelming majority of people to travel farther
and more often than ever before. The increase in air travel demand has been
more than 10 times the loss in rail
per capita travel since 1950. Trains are Not, in
Themselves, Essential Transportation Service: It was suggested that
Amtrak’s long distance services provide mobility between small towns, and that
this serves a need similar to that of the airline essential air service
program. In fact, however, Amtrak service is available only to the small
percentage of the nation’s communities that are, by chance, located along the
surviving historical passenger routes. Operating without subsidy, the nation’s
intercity bus companies serve at least four times as many communities and five
times as many passenger miles. The nation’s airlines serve more 30 percent more
locations (700 commercial airports) and nine times as many passenger miles. If
providing “essential transportation” were a genuine objective of public policy,
then it would be best achieved by awarding competitive franchises to whatever
mode, airline, bus or passenger rail, could provide the service for the least
amount of subsidy. Such a program would also be based upon objective criteria,
such as service to all communities exceeding a particular population threshold,
or a minimum distance from the commercial intercity transportation system (rail
station, bus station or commercial airport). But to consider intercity rail
itself as essential transportation service violates “equal protection of the
law,” by placing the interests of citizens living in communities along
passenger rail routes above those of the more numerous comparable communities
not so fortuitously located. Costly Passenger Rail Cannot
Provide Meaningful Redundancy: A related argument is that the nation needs
passenger rail for redundancy, especially in the aftermath of the September 11
terrorist attacks. This is a variation on the “essential transportation
service” argument. To the extent that transportation redundancy may be
required, intercity buses can provide four times the service as intercity rail
under the present structure. There is insufficient public funding for
meaningful levels of transportation redundancy to be provided by a passenger
rail system that is so non-cost competitive.
Operating Subsidies Violate
the Intent of ARAA: The Action Plan is
inconsistent with Congressional policy on operating subsidies, in suggesting
operating subsidies for long distance trains. The ARAA required that Amtrak
achieve operational self-sufficiency. Congress did not require self-sufficiency
by Amtrak in the expectation that the very organization formed to rule upon
Amtrak’s failure, ARC, would itself propose an Action Plan violating the operational self-sufficiency test. Like
other modes of intercity transport, long distance trains should be operated
only if they are valued enough by their customers to pay for them. Today,
intercity buses and airlines provide high levels of long distance service,
without subsidy. There is, in addition, a robust, unsubsidized commercial
market for long distance vacation travel, using charter buses, air packages and
even commercial rail tours, following the successful model of ocean cruise
lines. Envy is Not a Public
Purpose: An
even less compelling justification for subsidizing passenger rail is envy. It
is argued that passenger rail should be subsidized because other modes
(highways and the commercial air system) are subsidized. This is, however, a
fundamental difficulty with the “envy” justification --- at its core it is
fallacious. A
related argument is that other modes of transport received direct government
aid in their early years, and only later transitioned to user fee financing. In
that vein, it was argued during ARC deliberations that the proceeds from a 1943
to 1962 rail ticket tax (approximately $18 billion in 2000$, estimated from US Statistical Abstract data), spent for
general purposes, should be made available retroactively for passenger rail.
Contrary to the perception, before the interstate era, federal highway user
fees exceeded federal highway expenditures by more than $100 billion (1921 to
1956, In fact, Amtrak has already received $44 billion (inflation adjusted) in
federal funding, nearly 2.5 times the ticket tax revenue. Finally, passenger
rail service was the beneficiary of massive government support in its early
years, through land grants and other subsidies. Taxpayers should not have to
live in fear that special interests will successfully mine Treasury archives to
justify new spending on the pretext of revisionist interpretations that are
applied to repealed tax policies This would make federal tax policy even less
rational and fair. With
the exception of Amtrak, US intercity passenger transport is unsubsidized, both
operations and infrastructure. Federal expenditures on the intercity highway
and commercial air transport systems are fully supported with fees paid by
users (such as the gasoline tax and the airline ticket tax). User fees are
fundamentally different from public subsidies. This is illustrated by the
example of a municipally owned electric utility. Customers of the utility pay
for the service they consume. These payments are not subsidies; they are user
fees. The fact that the electric utility is government owned does not make user
payments a subsidy any more than payments to a privately owned utility are
subsidies. Subsidies involve general taxpayer support of consumption by users.
There is a simple test. A payment is a user fee if it is limited to the users
of a good or service. It is a subsidy if it is collected from the tax base in
general, without regard to use. Those who use highways pay for them. Similarly,
those who use airports pay for them. Those who do not use highways and airports
do not pay for them. It should be the same for passenger rail. If
an amount equal to Amtrak’s federal subsidy per passenger mile were applied to
air travel, the annual cost would be more than $35 billion (three times the
present revenues provided by users). The same passenger mile subsidy rate would
equate to more than $300 billion annually for highways (nearly 15 times the
federal revenue provided by personal vehicle users). Parity with the roadway
and air modes would require imposition of a ticket tax or other user fee on Amtrak users. It is the other intercity
modes, highways and commercial air transport that have intercity passenger rail
to envy in terms of public subsidies. But envy is not a legitimate public
purpose. A Cost-Competitive Passenger
Rail System Would be Profitable: Congressional intent under ARAA permits continued
federal capital subsidies, but does not require it. Indeed, there is evidence
that the national intercity passenger rail system does not need subsidies, operating or capital. Amtrak fares per
passenger mile are higher than that
of both airlines and intercity buses, neither of which is subsidized. Amtrak
costs per passenger mile are four times that of intercity buses and 3.5 times
that of airlines. Passengers already pay fares well above those of competing
intercity buses and airlines (above the market rate for intercity passenger
transportation). The subsidies simply finance Amtrak’s excessive, above market
costs. If Amtrak were cost-competitive,
the present service levels could be operated with no subsidy at all. Moreover,
Amtrak is losing ground in cost control. While airlines and intercity buses
have improved their performance over the past 25 years, Amtrak has become less
productive (Figure 4). Amtrak has not been under-funded, it has been over-funded, reflecting the reality
that Amtrak’s fundamental problem is not funding; it is cost control. The ARC Action
Plan appropriately addresses excessive costs by proposing competitive
franchising, but fails to recognize that, in the longer run, a cost competitive
passenger rail system would not require subsidies. The
Action Plan should have recommended phase out of subsidies (capital and
operating) for intercity passenger rail. Access to Infrastructure
Should be Commercial: The Action Plan would extend
the current operational priority for Amtrak trains over freight rail rights of
way. Further, the Action Plan would
extend the federal requirement that Amtrak receive discounted pricing for
infrastructure access, in effect taxing freight railroads to subsidize Amtrak.
Both of these provisions make freight railroads less competitive in their core
business, reducing their capacity to handle freight volumes. Extending these
provisions could force more rail freight business to trucks on the nation’s
highways. Among
high-income nations, only the United States and Canada have significant freight
rail operations. Even today, more ton mileage moves by rail than by truck in
the United States and Canada, in contrast to elsewhere in the high-income
world. There is little or no evidence that effective freight and passenger
rail systems can share the same rights of way in a modern nation. In
the last 30 years, US freight rail companies have reduced their rate of market
share loss to trucks by one-half. Rail ton mileage has nearly doubled. This has
been possible because freight railroads have had to contend with much less
interference from passenger trains since Amtrak began operations. It may be
surprising that freight rail trends have improved in the era of interstate
highways, during which it would have been expected that truck competitiveness
would have accelerated relative to rail. The
US experience is in stark contrast to elsewhere in the high-income world, where
rail freight market shares and ton-mile
volumes have fallen substantially. As a result, traffic congestion has become
much worse --- trucks account for double the US share of all traffic Europe and
five times the share in Japan. The high volume of trucks contributes to much
higher urban traffic congestion in Europe and Japan American
urban areas are already facing a serious highway traffic congestion crisis.
Political pressures have made it virtually impossible to provide the urban
highway capacity required to accommodate increasing travel demands. Federal
Highway Administration projections indicate that truck volumes will double in
the next quarter century, with a similar increase anticipated for freight
railroads. Because they occupy the space of nearly four cars on freeways,
trucks disproportionately contribute to urban traffic congestion. Moreover,
despite the training of professionalism drivers, higher truck volumes retard
highway safety. Trucks also contribute disproportionately to air pollution.
Passenger rail pricing and access policies that drive rail volumes to trucks can
only make the urban traffic congestion worse, with no material compensating
benefit. To control urban traffic congestion, passenger rail policy should
require access and pricing to be determined in the commercial market, not by
legislative or regulatory fiat. The Action
Plan should have recommended access and charges to be determined through
commercial processes, to maximize the urban highway traffic reduction potential
of freight railroads. Effective Standards Should
Apply to the Use of Air User Fees: The Action Plan raises the potential of using air
travel user fee revenues to support rail connections that would replace short
distance air services. Such a program could be subject to abuse. As currently
occurs in the transit program, local and state governments would be strongly
pressured by the rail construction/railcar builder/rail consultant lobby to
build systems that do not, in actual performance, achieve the purposes of the
program. Regrettably, state and local governments have been inclined to build
excessively costly infrastructure where federal funding is available. This is
evident, for example, in federal clean water, wastewater and transit programs,
where federal funding has been associated with unnecessarily expensive
technologies. Moreover, cost overruns, large subsidies and minimal impacts on
traffic congestion have been typical with respect to rail infrastructure. For
example, Britain’s under construction West Coast Main Line 140 mile per hour
upgrade project has been reported to Parliament to have risen in cost from $3.2
billion to nearly $10 billion. A
prerequisite to such use should be judicially reviewable findings that the rail
system is likely to be commercially viable (would pay operating costs, capital
cost and debt service from its own commercial revenues) and that substantial
and sustainable commercial airline operation reductions would be achieved.
These findings would be based upon planning studies, the projections of which
would be financially guaranteed by airport owners. Further, the use of air user
fees should be limited to securing debt. The local or state government airport
owners should be required to guarantee the self-sufficiency of any such rail
systems, paying any capital, debt service or operating shortfalls from their own
general tax base (not airport user fees or federal funds). In the case of
airports owned by regional authorities, the local government members should be
required to post full faith and credit financial guarantees. The
extent of air user fees that might be available for rail expansion is likely to
be limited. Increasing burdens are being placed on air user fee revenue
sources, with the need for expanding airports and improving security in the
aftermath of the September 11 terrorist attacks. Finally, there is considerable
question as to the potential for rail service to substitute for short distance
airline operations (above). The Action
Plan should have recommended strong safeguards to ensure that any use of air
user fee revenues is consistent with the purpose of air substitution. The Labor Provision is
Unfair: The
Action Plan would require labor
provisions beyond legal or contractual requirements. Amtrak employees already
have among the strongest labor protections in the nation. Amtrak labor
contracts provide for severance pay of up to 5 years, during which period
Amtrak continues to pay for medical and dental insurance. In contrast, US
Department of Labor surveys indicate that most US employees have no severance pay, much less continuing
health and dental benefits financed by former employers. Amtrak employees
already have superior separation benefits, which are ultimately guaranteed by
taxpaying workers who typically have little or no coverage themselves. At
average 1999 US employee compensation rates, this could approach an advantage
of up to $200,000 for individual Amtrak employees. Worse,
the Action Plan would require the
transfer of Amtrak labor contracts to new rail operators. A similar
“successorship” provision was rejected by an Amtrak-union arbitration panel in
1999 and is not in current Amtrak
labor contracts. Thus, the Action Plan
would grant Amtrak’s unions special privileges that they were unable to win in
the bargaining process. Further, the ARC labor proposal goes well beyond what
even Congress has been willing to grant to Amtrak’s unions. Concerns have
already been raised by Congressman James Oberstar, who offers wise counsel (in
a January 9, 2002 letter): … the Council seems to have
made promises to organized labor that it cannot possibly deliver. … This would
appear to greatly constrain the range of recommendations that the Council can
put forth. I certainly hope that the Council would be wise enough to simply
present its views, even if unpopular… Further,
the Action Plan labor protection
provision could sabotage state-based rail corridor projects intended to expand
passenger rail services. As services are transferred to the states, the overly
generous Action Plan provision would
impose higher than competitive unit costs. This would necessitate larger
subsidies, lower service levels or both. Passenger
rail’s potential can never be achieved if the interests of customers are
subservient to those of employees (or management). In the private sector,
businesses placing internal interests before customer interests fail. At
Amtrak, operations continue, costs rise and inordinately large revenues are
extracted from taxpayers for no public purpose. Amtrak employees should be
entitled to no greater protection than their already superior benefits. More
than that is both extravagant and unfair, especially in the era of Enron. The Action
Plan should have simply recommended labor protection consistent with current
labor contracts and applicable laws. Mr.
Chairman and members of the Subcommitte, thank you for the opportunity to
express these views.
|